Abstract
Based on the understanding of the interaction between
economic development and the development of science and technology, this writing
presents a philosophical analysis on the following topics: 1) the scientific
and technological contribution to periodic economic difficulties in the market
economy; 2) the economic challenges we would face to when the new wave of
industrial revolution through automation comes in the near future. Some
critical questions are raised and discussed.
1.
Introduction
One of the fundamental concerns of economic studies is to help
the society to be better prepared for potential economic uncertainties, no
matter through simple demand and supply analyses, advanced mathematical
modeling, statistical investigation, or various types of numerical simulations.
Many factors have been viewed as important causes for different levels of
economic uncertainties such as unforeseeable or uncontrollable natural
disasters, political turmoil, war, as well as individual situations created by
normal competitions or irrational fights between rivals during market
competitions, and so on. Even though sometimes an adverse condition for some
economic entities is caused by activities of other entities for their own sake,
none of these conditions would be universally considered favorite. However, there
is one universal goal of all economic entities in market economy which is
intrinsically creating perpetual economic uncertainties for the whole market.
That is the goal of reducing cost of human resources. On the other hand, an
ultimate of goal of social economic growth is to increase the living standard
of ordinary citizens in a society, which is also supposed to be the ultimate
goal of economics scholars including people who simulate economic systems by
numerical computations. This goal of increasing public living standard in
general would no doubt increase per capita cost for employers who hire people
for their businesses.
Therefore, it is not hard for us to see that the combination
of the ultimate goal of economic growth of a society and the fundamental goal
of reducing cost of every single business owner would end up with the
temptation of reducing the size of employees unless the increase of the size of
business would create the need of maintaining or even increasing the size of
employees. While the temptation of lowering business cost through reducing the
size of employees is very clear and certain, the need of increasing the size of
employees is highly contingent. That is the catch. Even if the size of business
increases the need of increasing the size of employees is not guaranteed, but the
temptation of reducing cost would always exist. Consequently, any economic
system would autonomously generating incessant economic uncertainties as a
result of the conflict between the common goal of collective growth of economic
welfare and the universal goal of cost reduction by stake holders in the system.
This autonomous source of economic uncertainties from within economic
development itself is worth special attention by professionals who intend to
make economic predictions through analytic or numerical studies.
2.
Mutual influence between economic development
and the development of science and technology
The development of science and technology has been a major
driving force to the economic development in modern societies. One positive
aspect of the scientific and technological impact upon social economy is that
it would potentially create the need of human workforce to conduct new
scientific researches, to develop, produce, transport and store, and then sell new
industrial products, to provide various services, and to manage all relevant
activities. This would no doubt help the economy of a society by boosting
employment in general. One important reason for the needs of increasing human
workforce would be the emergent needs of new products and services as the
results of new scientific and technological breakthroughs, which would offer
convenience in everyday life or improve the quality of human life or enhance
human capacity to deal with natural or social challenges. Examples include
internet services, personal tablets, smart phones and scientific way of growing
crops or scientific way of healing and many many more.
However, one type of scientifically created industrial
means, in the form of hardware or software, plays a very special role in
economic processes, which is the type of means that helps either to increase
productivity or facilitate and advance management tasks in workplaces[1],[2],[3].
The industrial applications of automation and information technology could
provide typical examples of this type. Even though the production and
application of products of this type would also create needs of human workforce,
they are often designed with clear motives of replacing human operations with the
work of machines and computers. As a matter of fact, because of the logical
possibility of replacing human operations by machines as a result of the
development of robotic technology and some forms of information technology, the
purpose of using machines in workplace becomes very different from what people
might have in mind a couple of centuries ago[2].
On the other hand, the local, regional, and global economic
development would boost scientific and technological development, including
original discoveries and inventions. This is not only because economic
activities would bring up new practical needs that would demand and stimulate
scientific and technological innovations, but also because economic development
would help scientific and technological activities in the following two
important aspects: 1) economic development would accumulate sufficient wealth
to support advanced and systematic scientific and technological researches and
innovations; 2) industrialized production and commercialized circulation would
provide the material and human resources that are of critical importance for
scientific and technological development.
Therefore, the economic development and the development of
science and technology would together form a mutually dependent dynamic system
(which we might call it as economic-scientific-technological system). Within
this system the development of science and technology bears two economically
conflicted mandates: 1) to improve life quality and working ability of a
society, and 2) to reduce the use of human beings in the existing working units
(and thus reduce employment) in the society. Obviously, if economic development
could never create new jobs to compensate the reduction of jobs due to the
development of science and technology, then the development of science and
technology would keep ruining the economy by continuous removing jobs from the
system and thus potentially reduce the societal buying power which would in
turn hurt the business owners in the system.
Even if the system could adjust itself to create new jobs to
make up the vacancies created due to the reduction of jobs by the development
of science and technology, there would be a lag between the time when old jobs
were lost and the time when new jobs are created. The main reason is because
while the removal of jobs after the adoption of new technology might be
inevitably driven by legitimate financial concerns, the creation of new jobs is
quite contingent at a given moment. Therefore, the equilibrium between the
reduction and creation of jobs due to the economic development and the
development of science and technology is a dynamic equilibrium with periods of
low job needs during which the needs of human resources are relatively low. The
periods of low job needs would autonomously occur in individual businesses when
the needs of human resources are reduced through the adoption of some new
technology. If the occurrences of the low job needs are random across the
system, then it might have minor impact upon the overall economy since when
some businesses are reducing the size of human resources some other businesses
might be increasing the size of human resources. However, if some common wave
of technological development causes a wide-spread low job needs at the same period
of time then the system might experience some more serious economic shock upon
its job market (and thus the public buying power) due to the scientific and
technological development.
This tells that in addition to some other factors that might
cause periodical economic slowdown or even crises, the autonomous self-evolution
in the system of economic development and scientific and technological
development might also contribute to periodical economic difficulties. That
might raise some concerns about what we can do about it or, more seriously, whether
we can always pull ourselves out of the period of low job needs caused by the
development of science and technology and then reach the dynamic equilibrium.
3.
A special competition
Because of the potential removal of jobs from market by the
development of the fundamental driving force of modern economy---science and
technology, one perpetual challenge to market influencers such as politicians,
economists, social activists, as well as enterprises would be how to balance
the loss of jobs resulting from the development of science and technology with
the creation of jobs through the creation of social needs. Or more profoundly
speaking, the challenge is how to balance between the material aspect of the
evolution of civilization, represented by science and technology, and the
humanity aspect of the evolution of civilization, symbolized by the general
living quality of the public around the world.
There have been two types of idealistic thinking about how
to balance these two aspects of human civilization, one is positive and one is
negative. The negative one is to stop or manually delay the development of
science and technology in order to maintain high level of demand of human
workforce in the market; and the positive one is to make some artificial
arrangement so that we might maintain high demand of human workforce while
enjoy the advantage of technology. The following paragraph by Shaiken,
the author of “The Human Impact of Automation”[1]is a typical example along
this idealistic line:
The real choice is
developing computer technology such that within the workplace, the technology
utilizes the extraordinary talents human beings can contribute. And, outside of
the workplace, utilizing technology in a way that shares the gains in
productivity so that unemployment is not the consequence of technological
change. In both areas, there has been remarkably little exploration of the
unstated assumptions underlying the utilization of technology or the
alternatives. To use computer technology in a human way - to realize its
extraordinary potential to enrich jobs and provide increased productivity for
the society - requires a careful, thorough exploration of the alternatives, and
the placing of human beings at the central point of the equation rather than as
an afterthought.
However, both of these types of idealistic thinking would
not work, at least not work for capitalist free market economy. This is because
they are against social laws of human civilizations, especially social laws in
capitalist society. In fact, no matter capitalists, socialists, communists, or
any other-ists have so far viewed science and technology as most important force
driving the evolution of civilization. Therefore, any effort of systematically
hindering or delaying the general development of science and technology for the
sake of employment would not attract much support around the world and thus
would not succeed. Similarly, any artificial restriction of application of
newly developed technology in workplaces solely for the purpose of balancing
the usefulness of technology and the employment needs would not work, at least
would not work in capitalist economy since it is against the principle of free
market.
Therefore, at least for capitalist market economy, creating
jobs to compensate the loss of job due to the development of science and
technology becomes a separate task that would not concern the people who work
for the development of science and technology. Now we can see a competition
between two relatively independent (but still mutually coupled to certain
extent) tasks: scientific and technological development and job creation. This
is a very special competition because it is basically driven by the development
of science and technology and thus it is more like a relay than a competition.
But it is a competition in the sense that the development of science and
technology would not pause to wait for the creation of jobs to catch up.
We are now facing such two questions: 1) Are there any
general patterns for the creation of new jobs when large amount of jobs are
lost due to the development of science and technology? 2) Can we always pull
ourselves out of the period of low job needs by creating new jobs to compensate
the loss of jobs in time?
For the past few centuries, human beings have experienced
many times of mass replacement of human operators by machines due to new
technology revolutions. But each time the job market recovered shortly after
new job positions were created because of the emergence of new social needs with
greater market demand of products or services and thus it just appeared to be a
transition from one social living style to another except for the disruptions
by a few regional or global wars. A very common pattern during those transitions
is that some new industrial products (software or hardware) were created which brought
up new demand of human workforce in the new line of design, production, storage/supply,
and sales/services. Within this pattern there are two basic factors: 1) new
products or services are of values to the society therefore there would be
market demand of them; 2) the production of the products and the provision of
services need human workforce.
Obviously, the second factor mentioned in the above
paragraph, i.e. the emergence of new needs of human workforce due to the
emergence of new market demand of products and services, is critical for the
recovery of job market. However, the main difference between the upcoming new
wave of the industrial revolution and any of the previous ones is that it aims
at a radical (if not complete) replacement of human workforce by robots or
general computer systems. This would make it a really meaningful question whether
we can still pull ourselves out of the period of low job needs once the mass
automation revolution comes in the near future from now.
If one day, as a result of highly advanced and extensive
automation, all production and service jobs would be done by robots, and human
beings would just enjoy life (or maybe enjoy fighting or killing each other),
then the answer to the question of last paragraph would be simple: we would
never pull ourselves out of the period of low job needs. This would obviously
create a trouble to market economy if there are still about one hundred million
people on this globe. This is because that based upon the rule of game of free
market economy people earn their rights to consume through transactions. When a
person gets food through a transaction, he pays money to the party that offers
food; and then he needs to offer something he owns through some transaction to
replenish his own supply of money. For most people the main thing they could
offer for money is their own labor for white or blue collar jobs. Once the
demand for human labor for white or blue collar jobs are eliminated by robots
and general computer systems, then most people might lose their capability to
purchase and thus to lose their right to consume, which would in turn to reduce
the general buying power in the market.
Of course there would still be an extreme scenario which
would validate the free market economy game even when no human labor for white
or blue collar jobs is needed. In this scenario most people own some
robot-operated companies that would provide goods and services to make money
for them. But the chance for human civilization to directly enter such scenario
after the automation revolution comes is not very high. This warrants that
human beings might need some sophisticated philosophical thinking to solve
their potential problems of social distribution of wealth before they could be
ready to embrace the coming of new wave of automation revolution. So far in
human history the capitalist system has been the most efficient economic system
since some other trial systems have failed in the history. But it might become
a question whether a simple capitalist system would continue to be efficient
when the new industrial revolution through automation would come. If yes, then
we might need to understand why before we accept the answer; if no, then we
need to think about how we could help to improve.
4.
Closing words
The development of science and technology is not only the miracle
producer for the economy in a very positive sense but also a most unpredictable
intrinsic source of economic uncertainties, especially for free will and
transaction based market economy. One of the biggest challenges economists and
the ordinary public might need to prepare to embrace in the near future would
be the coming era of highly automated industrial production by robots and much
more efficient computerized services and management operations without the need
of the presence of Homo sapiens.
This would no doubt have a fundamental impact upon the existing economic
theories.
As Shaiken noticed[1], “engineers,
particularly in academia, who deal with control or automation issues relating
to the workplace, have remarkably little contact with those directly affected
by design decisions - that is, workers and first-line supervisors in
production.” This social phenomenon is indeed very natural and would be
staying the same in the future since it really should not be a concern of those
engineers to preserve jobs of others in workplace. Rather, “automation does not assist, but
replaces human operators” as pointed out by Srivastava the author of “AUTOMATION – Its Impact on our
Lives”[3]. However, the issue of the replacement of human operators by
automation has to be one of the major concerns of economists and market influencers
around the world. Or more precisely it should be an undeniable responsibility
of economists and market influencers around the world to understand the nature
of the issue and search for solutions to deal with the issue. The brief
discussion presented in this writing is intended to offer a contribution to
such understandings and searches.
[1] Harley
Shaiken, "The Human Impact of Automation", Dec 1986, IEEE Control
Systems Magazine. URL:
http://www.ieeecss.org/CSM/library/1986/dec1986/w03-06.pdf
[2] Andrew
URE, "The Philosophy of Manufactures; or An Exposition of the Scientific,
Moral, and Commercial Economy", 2nd Edition, Charles Knight,
Ludgate-Street, London.
[3] Ankit
Kumar Srivastava, "AUTOMATION–Its Impact on our Lives", URL:
http://www.computing.dcu.ie/~asrivastava/docs/Automation.pdf
|