The politics of membership in
regional diplomatic, financial and trade groups, by Shintaro Hamanaka. London
and New York: Routledge. 2009. 234 pp. ISBN13: 978-0-415-55304-9.
Reviewed
by Jing Zhao, Sr. Fellow, US-Japan-China Comparative Policy Research Institute,
USA. June 2012.
Since
the words “regionalism” and “Asian regionalism” are not well defined or
recognized terminology, the book title confused me. As indicated in the
subtitle, the book actually is about chronology of (confusing, again) “Asian
diplomatic regionalism” (chapter 2), “Asian financial regionalism” (chapter 3),
and “Asian trade regionalism” (chapter 4) from a Japanese perspective. It would be a little helpful to know that
this is one of 42 books in Sheffield Center for Japanese Studies / Routledge
series, edited by Glenn Hook. Hook
himself wrote or edited 10 books in the series. While I cannot say anything
about other books of the series, this book under review is a disappointment. I regret to receive this book to review.
Since
the book is about the confusing “Asian regionalism,” Hamanaka has to explain
his hypothetical theory (Introduction and chapter 1). Hamanaka starts this book with an old Chinese
citation in the fourth century BC: “It is better to be the head of a small
group than to hold a less powerful position in a large group.” He then develops
his hypothetical theory based on more confusing concepts such as “mainstream
theories in explaining Asian regionalism,” (p.11) “neoliberal institutionalism,”
(p.14) “constructivism,” (p.15) “hegemonic stability theory” (p.17). Furthermore, I am totally lost in reading
Hamanaka’s boundaries figures (p.23 and p.26). It is waste of time to try hard
to figure out what Hamanaka wants to show readers of his knowledge of the
region.
It
is easy to point out that Japan’s post-war success in the region (under this
book’s coverage) is mainly because of this fact: the Japanese ruling class was
completely defeated, so they became humble not to take any powerful position.
Any leadership Japan tried to seek, either toward South Korea, Taiwan,
Southeast Asian countries, or with China, was under the frame of the
U.S.-Japanese security treaty in which Japan enjoyed and benefited greatly a
junior partnership position. A wise investor
will buy a cheaper house in a wealthy community rather than a relatively
expensive house in a poor community. In
this regard, the post-war Japanese ruling class made a wise and fortunate
choice (the so-called “Yoshida doctrine,” seeking no leadership). If I am the supervisor or editor, I would not
encourage Hamanaka study along the wrong assumption. Professor Hook might include Hamanaka’s
unique theory as one chapter in one of his numerous Japanese study
publications.
That said, for
English-speaking students of post-war Asian financial history, who do not know
Japanese language, this book may provide some useful translation material. |